Archives

  • 2018-07
  • 2018-10
  • 2018-11
  • 2019-04
  • 2019-05
  • 2019-06
  • 2019-07
  • 2019-08
  • 2019-09
  • 2019-10
  • 2019-11
  • 2019-12
  • 2020-01
  • 2020-02
  • 2020-03
  • 2020-04
  • 2020-05
  • 2020-06
  • 2020-07
  • 2020-08
  • 2020-09
  • 2020-10
  • 2020-11
  • 2020-12
  • 2021-01
  • 2021-02
  • 2021-03
  • 2021-04
  • 2021-05
  • 2021-06
  • 2021-07
  • 2021-08
  • 2021-09
  • 2021-10
  • 2021-11
  • 2021-12
  • 2022-01
  • 2022-02
  • 2022-03
  • 2022-04
  • 2022-05
  • 2022-06
  • 2022-07
  • 2022-08
  • 2022-09
  • 2022-10
  • 2022-11
  • 2022-12
  • 2023-01
  • 2023-02
  • 2023-03
  • 2023-04
  • 2023-05
  • 2023-06
  • 2023-08
  • 2023-09
  • 2023-10
  • 2023-11
  • 2023-12
  • 2024-01
  • 2024-02
  • 2024-03
  • 2024-04
  • 2024-05
  • br Conclusion A very important issue about demand led growth

    2018-11-13


    Conclusion A very important issue about demand-led growth macroeconomic models regards the possible constraints to this kind of growth. The sraffian supermultiplier states that, assuring the T-5224 conditions, capacity output growth respond to and is sufficient to meet effective demand. One possible constraint to demand-led growth could be balance-of-payment long run sustainability, and there is a vast tradition of models following the Kaldor-Thirlwall approach that deals with this issue.
    Introduction Since the overcoming of the razor\'s edge problem proposed by Kaldor (1955), post-Keynesian theorists have been working on long-term macroeconomic problems. However, unlike the Solow solution (Solow, 1956), the model proposed by Kaldor (1955) necessarily depends on there being at least two income classes, namely, capital and labor. This dependence results from the flexibility of the propensity to save that is no longer an exogenous constant and becomes dependent on the distribution of income between capital and labor, which hypothetically, will have a different propensity to save. Thus, if the propensity to save part of the profit is greater than the propensity to save part of the wages, there will be a distribution of income between capital and labor that will cause the average propensity to save in economics solve the problem raised by Harrod (1939) and Domar (1946). In the same research line, Pasinetti (1962) proposes a new model with the existence of two social classes, the capitalists and the workers. This change comes from the observation that individuals must have one only propensity to save, regardless of whether the source of their income is derived from capital or labor. Although Pasinetti (1962) works with the definition of personal income distribution (between capitalists and workers) in place of functional income distribution (between capital and labor) as Kaldor (1955), his work resulted in the same solution to the problem of “razor\'s edge” and reached the same equation for the rate of profit: (1) P/K=g/s, where P is the mass of profit, K the capital stock of the economy, g the natural growth, and s the propensity to save of the profit (in Kaldor) or of the capitalist (in Pasinetti). Two important issues related to the macroeconomic model of Kaldor–Pasinetti concern, first, to the implications of the introduction of the government on determining the long-term interest rate (Cambridge equation) and personal income distribution and, second, the compatibility of macro model results (with and without government) with the Orthodox microfoundations. To deal with the first problem, Steedman (1973), Dalziel (1989) and Pasinetti (1989a,b) insert the government activity in the Kaldor–Pasinetti model assuming that the government collects direct and indirect taxes, and makes transfers to the workers. In opposition to Steedman (1973), Dalziel (1989) and Pasinetti (1989a,b) admit that the government\'s savings is not necessarily equal to zero. The results found by Steedman (1973) and Pasinetti (1989a,b) show that both the long-term interest rate of the economy, determined by the Cambridge equation, as the share of income profits come to depend positively on tax profits (t). To Dalziel (1989), the government\'s insertion does not change the interest rate nor does it affect the functional income distribution. Although there is a disagreement over the effects of the taxation of the profits, the fundamental results of the Kaldor–Pasinetti model are kept in all these works, that is, the interest rate and income distribution depend fundamentally on the natural growth rate (g) and the propensity to save of the capitalists (s). Regarding the second issue, Baranzini (1991) proposed a microfoundation of the model of growth and income distribution of Kaldor–Pasinetti from the use of utility functions of two representative agents, one a capitalist and the other a worker. In this model, Baranzini (1991) uses economies where individuals save for the life cycle and may save for their descendants (the next generation). Thus, by capitalists and workers maximizing intergenerational utility functions with life cycle, Baranzini (1991) comes to a series of new equilibrium results. Particularly in the discrete version of the model, the equilibrium capital ratio belonging to each class is obtained and it is possible to calculate the total capital stock of the economy. In addition, the propensity to save of the capitalists and workers are no longer exogenous as in the Kaldor–Pasinetti model and they begin to depend on the parameters of the individuals’ preferences. An important result is the attainment of the equilibrium interest rate, as well as in the original models of Kaldor–Pasinetti, independently of any technology represented by a production function.